One Man's Trash

Norman Leahy


 

You Call This Conservative?

 

A self-proclaimed "conservative" transportation plan appears to be animated by the conviction that Virginians really don't know what's good for them. When did conservatives become central planners?


 

A couple of weeks ago, a group of conservatives issued what they called a “Conservative Transportation Alternative.” It got a bit of notice and even a bit of praise for its approach to the commonwealth’s evergreen transportation problems.

 

However, after reading the document, I am left asking one of those “first things” kind of questions, namely, is this plan really conservative? And even more, would this plan do much, if anything, to improve Virginia’s transportation system?

 

The first question is really one of perspective. In general, conservatives believe in a government structure that is both limited in its scope and powers, and thus is able to live within its proscribed fiscal means. On that account, the plan is hardly one that most conservatives would recognize as either embracing or advancing those ideas.

 

One of the biggest stumbling blocks is the plan’s seeming infatuation with, and disdain for, development, which is derisively termed “sprawl.” Now “sprawl,” as commonly understood, is caused by two things: increasing population and/or increasing prosperity. Opponents of “sprawl” face the unenviable task of trying to control either population growth or a rising standard of living. Attempts at controlling either can be quite unpopular in a free country.

 

The use of the term “sprawl” begs several questions, but the most fundamental is: What is the proper role of government? The author of this plan makes the tacit assumption that individuals -- exercising their freedom of choice -- are somehow making life too inconvenient for VDOT. By choosing to live in homes they can afford in communities they find desirable, the author implies that what we really have is a bad case of market failure. People want affordable homes. Developers are building willy-nilly wherever land is cheap. The old systems cannot keep up with this dynamic and everyone suffers. Like generations of central planners before him, the author believes that addressing this failure requires development decisions be taken out of the hands of individuals and transferred to governments.

 

The idea of wedding land use and transportation policies at the local level has a definite allure for some. It makes things neater, it makes them more predictable. It cannot be any worse than the status quo, can it?

 

Though consider this: Several counties in Northern Virginia and elsewhere are doing all they can to stop growth. In part, this is a reaction to what some believe was unwarranted and ill-considered expansion in recent years.

 

While this political turn may be short lived, the decisions made while it is in force will have long-term consequences. Giving local governments additional powers to enact policies that further their momentary political ends – in this case, through control of road construction -- would make it even easier for them to halt growth within their own borders.

 

You want a new subdivision? We’d like to help, really, but we can’t get the roads out to you right now. Sorry. Have you tried the county next door?

 

Thus, while they achieve their own end of halting growth, they have created an incentive for builders and home seekers alike to build and buy even further out in counties that have fewer growth restrictions. Has the more restrictive county actually solved its road problem? Most likely not. Those residents in the far-flung counties still have to get to work. They will still want to go into “town” to see friends, attend events and much more. In other words, they may not be able to buy a home in the restrictive county, but they will most certainly use its roads.

 

So, to the extent we give local governments powers over land and transportation, we increase the odds that congestion will get worse. People will have to drive far more, over greater distances, to get to their jobs. This not only puts more people on the roads at all times of day, it acts as an additional tax upon them (through lost personal time and productivity). The process continues until those rural counties decide they want to enact restrictive zoning and transportation policies, forcing people to move even farther out than before.

 

In addition, let’s not kid ourselves about the wisdom of local government land use policies. Henrico County is held up as a model of local land use and transportation integration. However, a small item that came along with last fall’s election results ought to give us all pause:

The election came close on the heels of news that a federal investigation is under way into prices the county paid developers for land.

 

While no School Board member or Board of Supervisors member has been publicly identified as a target of the investigation, incumbents McBride and Myers acknowledged recently that they have been subpoenaed to testify.

If that’s in a county with a good reputation for management, one can only imagine what might occur in a county that is somewhat less reputable. Linking land use and road building at the county courthouse, then, is not without its pitfalls, or its potential for grievous mischief. Conservatives should, by nature, be leery of concentrating power in any government entity. Local governments are no exception.

 

What about the other portions of the “conservative” plan?

 

There was this:

Compounding this factor is the tendency of our transportation funding approach to encourage an increase in daily trips by automobile, vehicle miles traveled by automobile, and the number of lane miles added to the state secondary road system in the form of new subdivision streets. Each of these factors has contributed to widely scattered development, which in turn makes transportation solutions more difficult and expensive  to provide.

What does this mean? Your guess is as good as mine. An earlier version of the plan made the rounds and struck a far different tone. In an earlier draft, this particular section railed against adding more capacity, which is baffling, because VDOT itself has added very little new road capacity in many years. Now it’s reduced, again, to a matter of sprawl.

 

The author seems to be troubled by development, which is odd, considering that developers have added road capacity as they build new homes and businesses. Under the current system, these roads, once completed, are added to the Virginia Department of Transportation’s grid, and then the folks at VDOT take responsibility for maintenance. Does this place a burden on VDOT’s budget? Sure. Just the same, under the current, Byrd-era system, VDOT is on the hook for such maintenance. Should it be? No. Even so, breaking up the anachronistic system of a bygone era is a political problem – one Virginia’s political class seems unwilling to face because the current system – for all its flaws – is not without its political benefits.

 

Nevertheless, on we go, looking for the conservativism. Maybe it’s here:

Elected officials have been too quick to pass over the most equitable, efficient and disciplined option for paying the staggering cost of transportation projects. That option is       tolls or other user charges, land or cash contributions by adjacent property owners who will benefit or other methods of having special beneficiaries rather than taxpayers pay for new projects.

This is the only proactive section of the entire plan. It recognizes that tolls may be needed. And while tolls and congestion pricing are important tools that must be considered, it’s important to realize that tolling is just that: A tool. It is not a silver bullet. And in Virginia, it faces a number of political obstacles.

 

The state’s major road corridors have been built and paid for through other means. Maintaining these roads is the difficult question. The tolerance, public and political, for adding tolls to such roads is very small. A plan floated to toll existing roads and bridges in Northern Virginia suggested that nearly $3 billion could be raised for transportation projects. While the figure is enticing, its chances of coming to pass are close to zero. Drivers who have paid, and continue to pay, state and federal gasoline taxes are highly unlikely to want to pay a second or third time for the same routes.

 

Virginia has considered and rejected tolling on roads like I-81 and others when debating transportation fixes in previous legislative sessions. Businesses fought the idea as did local road users. The idea was mothballed.

 

So, where can we toll? New construction is a likely option, but even here, there are problems. Tolls can only be economically justified if there is sufficient traffic to generate enough money to maintain the road. That leaves very few options – tunnels and bridges being the notable exceptions. Tolls could also possibly be applied to HOT lanes, where congestion could justify the cost.

 

But even if we overcome the bias against tolls, we must still overcome the politics of road funds. Some toll roads might be capable of generating large amounts of cash. And like the sweetest nectar, this money will attract all sorts of eager government bees, looking for a taste. The most likely result would be a diversion of toll funds away from road maintenance and into any number of other projects that do not benefit the toll payers.

 

For example, monies from the Dulles Toll Road are being used to support a multi-billion dollar rail project. This means toll paying drivers, who have at least the expectation that their toll money will be used to maintain the road, are instead being taxed to subsidize rail passengers.

 

Even on tolled HOT lanes, $132 million of the monies generated there may be transferred to support bus transit. Again, drivers will be subsidizing bus riders, and the tacit promise that their money will be used for road maintenance is undermined to suit the needs of transit-obsessed planners.

 

The report in many ways relies upon the Bush Administration for support of its argument on congestion pricing. Yet even under the Administration’s proposals, those funds will not be used to build more capacity or maintain roads. They are a simple tax. Does that make this Virginia plan anti-tax? Not really. It merely uses the idea of tolls to cover the very real wealth transfers that are already occurring.

 

The nagging impression I get from reading this plan is that it’s scarcely a conservative vision because it assumes people are incapable of making decisions about where and how they want to live. Those decisions must be made by “communities” and VDOT. If this is a conservative vision, then conservativism as we know it is dead. Rather, this is the vision of the anointed – the masses are too ignorant or too irresponsible to determine where they want to live, so let’s deny their freedom and make this choice for them.

 

It’s the last point that really makes this plan neither conservative nor an alternative to the existing transportation order. The bizarre assumption that development creates people, roads magically create cars, and both create congestion, ignores both biology and personal choice. People create people. They have families and want to live in homes they can afford that are somewhat close to work, and school, and more. Under this plan, people are inconvenient costs on VDOT’s balance sheet, but this can be easily remedied by taking away the citizens’ rights and freedoms, and by transferring power to local governments.

 

Development controlled. The demand for roads controlled. Prosperity controlled. Population controlled. These are not conservative ideas. They are the dreams of a central planner.

 

-- April 7, 2008

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Contact info

 

Norman Leahy is vice president for public affairs at Tertium Quids, a conservative, nonprofit advocacy organization.

Read his profile here.

 

Contact:

   normanomt[at]

      hotmail.com