Bacon's Rebellion

James A. Bacon



Dearth of Water -- Or Ideas?

H20 may be the most abundant molecule on earth, but it's still subject to supply and demand. When there's not enough, local governments should raise the price.


 

Last week, in response to the drought, Gov. Mark R. Warner imposed water conservation restrictions on most of the state. His measures seemed reasonable as far as command-and-control measures go, and the populace appeared to accept them as a necessary evil. Despite the threat to suburbia's water-guzzling ways, there are no outraged soccer moms busting open water mains, no Yuppies massing SUVs in the public square to hose them down in demonstrations of solidarity and protest.

 

Although few Virginians are defying the emergency restrictions openly, it’s not clear that everyone is willing to sacrifice their Tall Fescue for the public good. In the Richmond area, where I live, local governments have levied fines against a number of scofflaws who didn’t get the message. One vigilante decapitated the spray nozzles from the offending hoses of his neighbors. Meanwhile, die-hard gardeners are going underground. One confided to me, somewhat guiltily, that she might run her sprinkler at night when no one would see it.

 

Surely, there must be a better way. There are two big problems with emergency water-conservation measures, whether those proclaimed by the governor or those instituted by localities across the state. First, the rules are enforced unevenly. Although most people comply with the restrictions, some evade them. Unless we turn into a commonwealth of snitches, there is no practical way to enforce the edicts uniformly. Second, there is no incentive to conserve water by adopting new technologies or best management practices. If you do what the governor says, you’re not obligated to do anything else.

 

Call me a sentimental old fool, but I can’t help but wonder: What ever happened to the free market? What’s wrong with using price as a mechanism to allocate scarce supplies of water? The governor can’t institute new rates – his emergency police powers don't allow him to administer local water authorities -- but localities can, and should, take a look at market mechanisms as tools for managing the drought.

 

A market-oriented approach would work something like this: The local utility department would calculate the daily volume of water that a reasonably parsimonious household would consume in essential functions related to nutrition and hygiene -- cooking, showering, brushing teeth, etc. Nationally, households consume about 300 gallons daily on average. A “drought” rate might be set at 250 gallons, not enough to be punitive but enough to remind people not to leave the faucet running.

 

Then create a second pricing tier for consumption of water above that required for basic needs. Charge enough for each extra gallon of water – perhaps 10 times the normal rate -- to capture peoples’ attention when the water bill arrives.

Once the water wasters stroke a $400 check, I guarantee that they’ll think twice about running the sprinklers and washing their cars.

 

Local governments would have to enact different rate schemes for commercial and industrial consumers, but the principle would be the same: Big water users should bear the burden of conservation – but they should be given flexibility to do so cost effectively. Personally, I don’t see why the governor exempted commercial car washes from his restrictions. A market-oriented approach would make them pay more for water like everyone else. They could either invest in water-saving equipment or pass on the higher cost to their customers. The world wouldn't fall apart if fewer people washed their cars. Similarly, we should stop chastising restaurants for serving water to their customers. Let the restaurateurs decide how best to conserve. Maybe installing water-efficient dishwashing machines would make more sense.

 

Special attention would have to be given to manufacturing plants that consume large volumes of water in their industrial processes. On the one hand, industry should shoulder some of the responsibility for conservation; other the other, localities don’t want to shut them down.

 

Under a market-based "drought pricing" scheme, several good things would happen. First, there would be no cheating and no need to tattle on neighbors who run their sprinklers at night. Utility departments would meter customers and charge them on the basis of how much water they consumed. End of story.

 

A second good thing is that households would have a monetary motive to use less water. It may be noble to conserve out of a sense of civic duty, but nothing focuses the mind like writing a big, fat check to the utility department every month. Also, it's easier for people to conserve when they can alter their behavior in ways that make sense to them – not in blind conformity to guidelines handed down from on high.

 

A third good thing is that some people might actually invest money in water-conservation measures – water-efficient appliances, drip irrigation systems, xeriscaping (the conservation of water through landscaping), whatever. These things all exist but Virginians, accustomed to inexpensive water, have never had to reason to use them. However, higher prices for water would increase the return on such investments.

 

If Governor Warner wants the state to take an activist role, he should enroll the Virginia Tech agricultural extension service -- or whatever’s left of it after the latest round of budget cuts -- to promote the virtues of xeriscaping. As they do in Texas, extension agents could educate Virginia’s suburbanites about the virtues of properly preparing the soil, mulching, contouring their gardens and selecting drought-resistant grasses and plants. The prospect of saving two or three hundred dollars a month in water bills just might induce a shift in landscaping preferences.

 

A fourth good thing about drought pricing is that higher prices will bring in extra revenues to local water authorities. One reason that the city of Richmond took so long in implementing conservation measures, according to press reports, is that the city couldn’t afford the loss of revenue. A prolonged decline in water consumption, if not offset by higher rates, could prove financially crippling for utilities that make bond payments to unforgiving investors. If some fat-cat business executive is willing to pay hundreds of dollars a month to preserve his lovingly tended, Chem-lawn treated sod, I don’t have a problem with that. He’s helping keep my water company solvent.

 

Even if water authorities aren't financially stressed, they can invest the added revenues in conservation measures of their own. Some older systems waste millions of gallons a year through leaky pipes. Implementing a drought-pricing rate structure might allow them to accelerate their maintenance programs. Water authorities with newer infrastructure might use the extra revenue to educate the public through “water efficiency” certifications on new homes, comparable to Dominion Virginia Power’s energy efficiency certifications, or to subsidize the installation of water-saving devices.

 

Admittedly, drought-pricing strategies take time to roll out and even longer to crimp the hose of water consumption. Governor Warner can’t afford to wait while local governments around the state debate the structures of such plans. He needs to act now.

 

But forward-looking localities should consider drought-rate pricing regardless. Virginia’s population continues to grow faster than the national average. What’s more, the pattern of development is increasingly land and water intensive: Large lots typically feature houses set amid vast expanses of emerald green turf. We may not see another drought like 2002’s for another century, but with growth putting greater stress on water supplies, even a modest shortfall in precipitation could prove disastrous a decade from now. Localities should put drought-pricing plans on the books and be ready to implement them the next time the need arises.

 

-- Sept. 3, 2002

                                           

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

Water Markets Need Meters

 

The Florida Water Conservation Initiative (April 2002) contains an interesting discussion of water pricing. Although public and investor-

owned utilities do a good job of metering water usage, the report concludes, smaller utilities and private wells do not. Furthermore, there is little metering of condominiums and apartment buildings. (You will need Adobe Acrobat to download this study.) The section on water pricing begins on p. 78.

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

 

The Art, and Science, of Xeriscaping

Xeriscaping has become an important landscaping movement in arid western states. (The word, from the Greek "xeri," meaning dry, was coined by a Denver environmental planner.) To get a feel for the discipline, visit High Country Gardens (link disabled) online catalog of plants for the western garden and check out its e-zine.